Hulton-Deutsch Collection/Corbis via Getty
Images
From Versailles to the Euro
The agreement that ended World War I, signed in
June 1919, imposed a ruinous debt burden on Germany. A century later, Germany
has assumed the role of the eurozone’s self-righteous creditor, fretting about
“moral hazard” and ignoring the destabilizing, contagious effects of making
debtor countries poorer.
LONDON – This month marks the centenary of the
Treaty of Versailles, one of the agreements that brought World War I to a
close. In a sense, the tables have turned. Whereas the treaty imposed huge
reparations on Germany, today’s Germany has taken the lead in imposing a large
debt obligation on its fellow eurozone member Greece.
Although the creditor-debtor cards have been
reshuffled since 1919, the game remains the same. Creditors want their pound of
flesh, and debtors want to avoid giving it. Debtors want their debts forgiven,
while creditors fret about “moral hazard” and ignore the destabilizing,
contagious effects of making debtor countries poorer. Sadly, the eurozone has
not learned the debt lessons of Versailles, or heeded the warnings of John
Maynard Keynes.
When World War I ended, the victorious allies
were determined that Germany should make “reparation” for the damage it had
caused in the war, partly to pay off the debts they owed one another. But they
failed to agree at Versailles on a final figure for the indemnity, instead
tasking a Reparations Commission to determine the amount by 1921.
The nub of the issue was how much Germany could
pay without an allied military occupation. In his 1919 polemic The Economic Consequences of the
Peace, Keynes
said that if Germany restricted its consumption, it could probably run an
annual trade surplus of $250 million, or 2% of its national income, which over
30 years would add up to $7.5 billion.
In May 1921, the Reparations Commission fixed
Germany’s indemnity at $33 billion. But the capital sum was effectively reduced
to only $12.5 billion, requiring annual repayments of $350 million. This trick
was accomplished by requiring Germany to issue three sets of bonds, but to pay
interest and principal on only the first two (Classes A and B), consigning
repayment of the “C” bonds to never-never land.
The charade of maintaining a large fictional
German debt while trying to extract repayment of a smaller “realistic” one
continued through the 1920s. In fact, Germany wasn’t prepared to repay the
realistic debt, either, and only did so following fresh loans. In 1926, Keynes
commented scathingly, “The United States lends money to Germany; Germany
transfers the equivalent to the Allies, the Allies pay it back to the United
States government. Nothing real passes.”
Then came the Wall Street crash and the Great
Depression, and foreign loans to Germany dried up. By raising taxes and cutting
public spending, Germany generated the required surplus to meet its annual debt
payments between 1929 and 1931, but at the cost of intensifying the slump. The
German economy shrank by 25%, and unemployment soared to 35%. The policy of
“fulfillment” under Chancellor Heinrich Brüning paved the way for Adolf Hitler,
who simply repudiated the debt.
Today’s debt charade in the eurozone has many
parallels with post-World War I Europe.
In the run-up to the 2008 global financial
crisis, southern European countries steadily accumulated debt by borrowing from
northern banks, mainly German, to finance risky construction projects. As long
as the boom continued, money kept pouring in. But when the crisis that began in
the US hit the eurozone, northern European banks refused to extend new loans –
forcing southern European governments to bail out their own banking sectors.
Greece was the most conspicuous victim of this
reversal. In 2009, the country’s budget deficit shot up to 15% of GDP, national
debt exceeded 100% of GDP, and ten-year Greek bond yields soared above 35%.
In 2010, the Greek government threatened to
default. The northern banks agreed to partial debt restructuring – mainly by
extending the repayment period – in conjunction with a €240 billion ($269
billion) credit line from a “troika” of the International Monetary Fund, the
European Central Bank, and the European Commission.
This funding enabled the Greek government to
meet interest payments, but it came with strict austerity conditions: higher
taxes, cuts in public spending (particularly pensions), the abolition of the
minimum wage, sale of assets, and curtailment of collective bargaining. In
theory, these measures would yield a trade surplus that would enable Greece to
repay its debt.
Between 2010 and 2015, Greece’s government,
like Brüning’s in Depression-era Germany, pledged itself to a policy of
“fulfillment.” In January 2015, voters finally revolted, electing a left-wing
government headed by the Syriza party, which had promised to fight the cuts.
But by August that year, Greece had capitulated to its creditors, enacting the
necessary austerity measures in exchange for a new €85 billion loan.
Since 2010, Greece has borrowed over €300
billion. As of January 2019, it had repaid €41.6 billion, with a repayment
schedule stretching beyond 2060. Official creditors are unlikely to get any of
their money back because the bulk of the Greek bonds are fictional, like the
German “C” bonds of the 1920s. Instead, taxpayers in creditor countries will
pick up the tab in the form of higher taxes and reduced public spending.
The orthodox view is that austerity worked in
Greece. Deprived of private loans, the country balanced its budget and moved in
six years from a trade deficit to a surplus.
But austerity has imposed horrendous
costs. Some 300,000
Greek civil servants were laid off, the economy shrank by 25%, and the jobless
rate rose to 25% (and youth unemployment to over 60%). Homelessness,
emigration, and suicide all increased. Greece’s debt-to-GDP ratio rose from
100% to 170%, and the creditors’ cartel will continue to control the country’s
economic policy until the debt is repaid.
As Keynes wrote in 1919 “The policy of
degrading the lives of millions of human beings, and of depriving a whole
nation of happiness should be abhorrent and detestable.” Later, he argued that
austerity was also theoretically wrong: cutting incomes in one country causes
incomes to fall elsewhere, spreading a depression and ensuring that any
recovery will be delayed and feeble.
The moral of these two stories, a century
apart, is that countries should avoid getting locked into creditor-debtor
relationships. If they cannot, then a fair bargain between creditors and
debtors is necessary to preserve social and political peace. The eurozone is
having to learn this lesson all over again.
Writing for PS since 2003
Robert Skidelsky, a member of the British House of Lords, is Professor Emeritus of Political Economy at Warwick University. The author of a three-volume biography of John Maynard Keynes, he began his political career in the Labour party, became the Conservative Party’s spokesman for Treasury affairs in the House of Lords, and was eventually forced out of the Conservative Party for his opposition to NATO’s intervention in Kosovo in 1999.
Robert Skidelsky, a member of the British House of Lords, is Professor Emeritus of Political Economy at Warwick University. The author of a three-volume biography of John Maynard Keynes, he began his political career in the Labour party, became the Conservative Party’s spokesman for Treasury affairs in the House of Lords, and was eventually forced out of the Conservative Party for his opposition to NATO’s intervention in Kosovo in 1999.
No hay comentarios.:
Publicar un comentario