https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/cooper-mundell-williamson-exchange-
rate-regimes-by-jeffrey-frankel-2021-04
What Three Economists Taught Us About
Currency Regimes
Apr 21, 2021JEFFREY
FRANKEL
Today, freely
floating exchange rates suit most large countries better than the late
economists Richard Cooper, Robert Mundell, and John Williamson thought. But
some countries do well with firmly fixed exchange rates, while at least half of
the world’s countries fall in between.
CAMBRIDGE – A
generation of great international economists is passing from the scene. Richard Cooper died on December 23, Robert Mundell on April
4, and John Williamson on April
11.
All three
made important contributions on a variety of topics, and coined memorable terms
that remain in use, though not always in their originally intended sense. More
specifically, all three played a role in the ongoing debate about optimal
currency arrangements. Each was unhappy with the system of market-determined
floating exchange rates and proposed reforms. Should central banks fix exchange
rates, or even abandon independent currencies entirely, as the members of the
eurozone have done? Or should they do something else?
Williamson
led the “something else” camp. He advocated intermediate
exchange-rate regimes that
provide more flexibility than fixed rates but more stability than free-floating
rates. One, the “crawling
peg,” a term that he coined, proved especially popular
in Latin America in the 1980s and early 1990s. Under this arrangement,
countries decide to live with inflation by undertaking monthly mini-devaluations
that keep their producers price-competitive internationally.
Williamson
also championed another intermediate regime, the target zone, under which
countries keep their exchange rates within pre-specified bands. He
repeatedly updated his proposals to apply the target zone even to the dollar, euro,
yen, and other major currencies.
But these
arrangements were most popular among emerging markets. Many mixed and matched
Williamson’s proposals – falling under the rubric of basket,
band, and crawl (BBC) –
as Botswana and Singapore still do today.
Williamson
was most famous for coining the expression “Washington Consensus” in 1989, to describe ten economic development
policies that he judged had the support of the International Monetary Fund, the
World Bank, and US administrations.
But he lost
control of his own invention. Williamson had explicitly excluded one
item from his policy list: the liberalization of financial controls to allow
the free movement of capital. Yet, most of those who subsequently used the
phrase “Washington Consensus,” typically to attack perceived “neoliberalism,”
have assumed that it was included.
Unlike Williamson, Richard Cooper favored fixed exchange rates. In 1984, he predicted that business would
eventually find the high volatility of floating rates “intolerable,” and proposed “the creation of a common currency for all of
the industrial democracies,” beginning with the United States, Europe, and
Japan.
Cooper
emphasized that his plan was only a long-term vision. But the political
appetite for giving up this degree of national sovereignty is even more
miniscule now than it was when he proposed his recipe.
In academia,
Cooper started the field of international macroeconomic interdependence and cooperation. He also put his ideas into practice, serving as
US under secretary of state for economic affairs in President Jimmy Carter’s
administration and playing an active role at the 1978 Bonn Summit of G7
leaders. There, Germany, Japan,
and the US agreed to act as locomotives, simultaneously pulling the rest of the
world economy out of stagnation. At this time, Cooper gave the world the term
“locomotive theory,” referring to coordinated fiscal expansion across
countries.
Mundell also
favored fixed exchange rates. He was awarded
the Nobel Prize in
economics in 1999 for two contributions regarding their pros and cons, relative
to floating rates. One was the 1962-63 Mundell-Fleming model, which was far ahead of its time in
assuming high cross-border financial integration. A key finding was that
monetary policy attains high power to influence income if a country’s exchange
rate floats, but loses power if the exchange rate is fixed.
The Nobel
committee also highlighted Mundell’s 1961 article, “A Theory of Optimum Currency
Areas” (OCAs), in which he
observed that there was no reason why national political boundaries should
necessarily coincide with the boundaries between independent currencies.
Mundell is
often called the intellectual father of two big and consequential ideas:
supply-side economics and a common European currency. The two movements were
very different. But both were associated with a relatively unconditional belief
in restoring exchange-rate stability.
As Paul Krugman has pointed out, it is essential to distinguish between Mundell’s work before and after 1971,
the year that the Bretton Woods system of pegged exchange rates broke down and
Mundell left the University of Chicago. His post-1971 ideas were broad-brush, and at odds with
those in his earlier writings. Mundell’s fundamental change of worldview was
most likely due to a new belief that the prices of goods and services were so
flexible as to equilibrate markets automatically, regardless of currency
policy.
From
Mundell’s post-1971 viewpoint, others misused his OCA concept. Many American economists liked his framework for assessing the
advantages and disadvantages of a common currency, but argued that European countries did not meet the OCA criteria. They found
that most individual European economies generally needed monetary autonomy more
than, say, the 50 US states did, because European countries’ business cycles
were relatively uncorrelated, and their unemployed workers were generally
unable to adjust to shocks by moving to where the jobs were.1
Mundell’s first choice was a single global currency. His second choice was currency union within Europe. Having originated the OCA criteria, he felt entitled to say whether proposed unions qualified. But subsequent events seem to confirm others’ warnings that even Europe, let alone the entire world, is too large to qualify.
As of 2021,
freely floating exchange rates suit most large countries better than Mundell, Cooper, and Williamson
thought. But at the same time, some smaller economies do well with firmly fixed
exchange rates.
At least half
of the world’s countries fall in between. But in most cases, their intermediate
exchange-rate regimes don’t obey such well-defined rules as Williamson’s BBC
scheme. For example, many larger emerging markets, including South Korea,
India, and China, pursue systematic managed floats.
As we mourn
the passing of these three giants, one recalls famous Keynes admonition:
“Practical men who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual
influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.” That may be so,
but it is no less true that the influence of powerful ideas can exceed what
their originators foresaw.
Writing for
PS since 2000
175 Commentaries
Jeffrey
Frankel, Professor of Capital Formation and Growth at Harvard University,
previously served as a member of President Bill Clinton’s Council of Economic
Advisers. He is a research associate at the US National Bureau of Economic
Research.
No hay comentarios.:
Publicar un comentario